Why Are Advisory Fees Lower Than They Have To Be?

Why are financial planning fee structures all over the map?
The answer, my friend, is blowing in the wind...

Bob Veres

How much should you charge for your services?  Is there any way to objectively calculate a fair price?  Doctors, lawyers and accountants all charge relatively similar prices for their services. Why does the financial planning profession have fees that are all over the map?

Most of us know that there are a lot of different fee structures out there, all being charged for essentially the same service.  Not long ago, an advisor decided to do a mystery shopper survey of his competition, posing as an investor who happens to have a $3.4 million portfolio.  He discovered something astonishing: with a little bit of diligent shopping, this client could pay anywhere from $750 to $44,200 a year for roughly equivalent planning work. 

The actual fees, recently updated, are broken out as follows:

Advisory Firm 1

 $2,500 for a financial plan and investment advice
(no ongoing fee, but annual portfolio checkups for $750).

Advisory Firm 2

  $7,000, or .21% of investible assets.

Advisory Firm 3

  $20,400, or 0.60%.

Advisory Firm 4

  $27,000, or 0.79%.

Advisory Firm 5

  $28,900, or 0.85%.

Advisory Firm 6

  $30,500, or 0.90%.

Advisory Firm 7

  $44,200, or 1.3%.


It does not take more than a few seconds with this chart to realize that Adam Smith’s invisible hand is clearly not working as effectively for planners in the free market as it is for, frankly, everything else.  In the rest of the world where products and services are bought and sold – in retail products and consumer durables, in commodities, plumbing, bricklaying, medicine and in any other consumer service you can think of – pricing anomalies like these get wiped out faster than you can say “comparison shopping.”

All else being more or less equal, whenever prices are this broadly dispersed, a flock of consumers should jam the doors of the least expensive advisory firms, whose principals would quickly become overwhelmed with new work and raise their fees in panicked self-defense.  The firms on the expensive side of the list, meanwhile, would be sitting by the phone wondering why no new business was coming their way.  Eventually, as the phone remained silent, they’d reduce their fees to something closer to the market norm.

Under the free market’s normal mechanisms, the cost of financial planning services would be forced into a much tighter pricing band than we see today.  Those who choose to charge more – even a lot more – than others are apparently having no more trouble finding customers/clients than those who have priced themselves down to the bare bone.  Something is not right.

This freedom has strange consequences.  Without the help of that Invisible Hand, advisors have to ask themselves the kind of business questions that no executive at Coca Cola or General Motors would ever think of asking.  Should we look at our cost of operations, and then determine our profit margins based on other service industries? Should we charge for our time or for what we know?  Should we factor in intangibles such as liability exposure?  Should the stock picker be paid more because she expends more resources to research stocks than the passive investment manager spends to put together a diversified asset class portfolio?

What would I feel comfortable charging my mother?

What economics professor would ever imagine that pricing and profitability in a competitive marketplace could be under the control of the provider to such an extent?